Use Sophia to knock out your gen-ed requirements quickly and affordably. Learn more
×

Aggregate Supply and Aggregate Demand

Author: Sophia

what's covered
This lesson will cover aggregate supply and aggregate demand. Specifically, this lesson will cover the following:

Table of Contents

1. Aggregate Supply/Aggregate Demand Model

Let’s begin by looking at the aggregate supply/aggregate demand graph. Note that, in microeconomics, the x-axis generally represents quantity (as in the quantity of one specific item), but here, it represents overall quantity or all output in an economy, which is GDP.

The y-axis represents the overall price level, not just the price of a specific item.

A graph depicting the aggregate supply/aggregate demand model. The horizontal x-axis represents the GDP, and the vertical y-axis represents the Price Level. The A S or S R A S curve starts at the origin (x equals 0, y equals 0) and slopes upward. The aggregate demand or A D curve begins at the endpoint of the y-axis and ends at the endpoint of the x-axis. The point at which the A S and the A D intersect is the equilibrium, which corresponds to the points Y* at the middle of the x-axis and P* at the middle of the y-axis. A horizontal dashed line from the point P* and a vertical dashed line from the point Y* extend to the equilibrium.

hint
This is the most common graph used in macroeconomics to show overall, or macroeconomic, activity.


2. Aggregate Demand

We will start by discussing aggregate demand (AD). It is the total amount of goods and services demanded in the economy at a specific point in time and at a prevailing price level.

Here is what an aggregate demand curve looks like. Recall that it is a downward-sloping curve and represents an inverse relationship between price level and real GDP.

A graph of an aggregate demand or A D curve represented by a line resembling the hypotenuse of a right-angled triangle. The x-axis is labeled ‘GDP’, whereas the y-axis is labeled ‘Price Level’. The A D curve slopes downward, beginning at the top of the y-axis and ending at the end of the x-axis.

This indicates that people will want to purchase more as the overall price level falls. So, as prices go down, people want to buy more. As prices go up, people want to buy less. However, it is important to note that when we say “people” want to purchase more, we are actually referring to different groups of people, which comprise the aggregate demand formula.

formula to know
Aggregate Demand
table attributes columnalign left end attributes row cell A D equals C plus I plus G plus left parenthesis X minus M right parenthesis end cell row cell w h e r e end cell row cell C equals C o n s u m p t i o n space o r space C o n s u m e r s space end cell row cell I equals I n v e s t m e n t comma space R e f e r r i n g space t o space B u s i n e s s e s space o r space F i r m s space end cell row cell G equals space G o v e r n m e n t s space end cell row cell X minus M equals E x p o r t s space M i n u s space I m p o r t s equals N e t space F o r e i g n space P u r c h a s e s space o f space D o m e s t i c space G o o d s end cell end table

If you recall from the lesson on GDP, GDP equals consumer purchases, investment outlays by businesses, government spending, and net exports. This is what comprises aggregate demand.

So, would aggregate demand really comprise the sum of all demand curves for everything in the economy? Well, sort of, but let’s think about it differently.

In microeconomics, demand curves slope downward because, as the price of something specific falls, people buy more of it. We cannot use this same analysis when looking at aggregate demand.

However, there are three reasons why aggregate demand slopes downward:

term to know
Aggregate Demand (AD)
The total amount of goods and services demanded in an economy at a specific point in time and at a prevailing price level.

2a. Wealth Effect

As prices in the economy fall, people feel like they are wealthier. Now, they would not necessarily be wealthier, but because their money can go further, people will tend to buy more.

The part of aggregate demand that is increasing here is the C component. Consumer purchases will increase because of the wealth effect as prices fall. The wealth effect is defined as the perception that wealth has increased, resulting in an increase in consumption, or the C component of the aggregate demand formula.

term to know
Wealth Effect
Perception that wealth has increased, resulting in an increase in consumption, C.

2b. Interest Rate Effect

As prices go down along the y-axis, this increases the amount of money circulating in the economy, which tends to drive down interest rates.

hint
Remember, interest rates are what we pay whenever we borrow money, so this likely will not impact consumer purchases of groceries or clothing, for instance.

As interest rates fall, people will buy more items that require loans, like cars, houses, appliances, and furniture—items considered to be durable goods.

Again, this is impacting that C component of the aggregate demand formula, though it refers to different types of consumer purchases—those requiring loans.

Also, falling interest rates will impact business investment. Businesses will take advantage of lower rates and invest more in their companies. Basically, we see C and I being impacted by anything that is interest-sensitive because of the interest rate effect as the price level falls.

Therefore, the interest rate effect dictates that as interest rates fall, consumption increases because of the decrease in the cost of borrowing. As a result, purchases and business investment (consumption, C, and investment, I, respectively) both increase.

term to know
Interest Rate Effect
As interest rates fall, consumption increases because of the decrease in the cost of borrowing; as a result, purchases and business investment (consumption, C, and investment, I, respectively) both increase.

2c. Exchange Rate Effect

Finally, aggregate demand curves slope downward because of the exchange rate effect. As price levels in the United States fall, our goods become relatively cheaper to foreigners because our exchange rate falls.

When that happens, foreigners will try to take advantage of this by buying more from us, so exports (X) are going to increase.

At the same time, as our exchange rate falls, our dollars will not go as far when purchasing items from other countries. Therefore, we buy less from other countries, and imports (M) decrease.

think about it
If you think about it, if X is increasing and M is decreasing, then our net exports are increasing. This is the (XM) portion of the aggregate demand formula—the component that increases as exchange rates fall when the price levels come down.

Exchange rate movements impact demand. Domestic currency depreciation—meaning that as our price level comes down, our exchange rate goes down—increases the cost of imports, resulting in a potential decrease in imports, or M. A lower domestic exchange rate also increases foreign demand for domestic goods, increasing our exports, or X.

term to know
Exchange Rate Effect
Exchange rate movements impact demand; domestic currency depreciation increases the cost of imports, resulting in a potential decrease in imports, M, while a lower domestic exchange rate increases foreign demand for domestic goods, increasing exports, X.


3. Aggregate Supply

Now let’s turn our attention to aggregate supply. There are two aggregate supply curves.

3a. SRAS

The aggregate supply curve on the graph at the beginning of this lesson is the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) curve. SRAS is the total amount of goods and services supplied in an economy in the short run.

In the short run, the aggregate supply curve does slope upward, as shown below.

A graph depicting the concept of aggregate supply or A S. The horizontal x-axis represents the GDP, and the vertical y-axis represents the Price Level. The curve for A S or short-run aggregate supply or S R A S starts at the origin (x equals 0, y equals 0) and slopes upward. The curve is represented by a line.

Again, aggregate supply is the total amount produced at various price levels. It slopes upward in the short run because businesses can actually produce more as price levels rise for several reasons:

  • They will not necessarily have to pay their workers more immediately. As prices go up, workers are eventually going to argue for higher wages because things will be more expensive and they will want more money. However, that does not happen immediately; it is an adjustment that takes some time. Therefore, businesses can produce more because they will not have to pay their workers more money immediately.
  • Businesses can also start drawing down their inventories. They can use up the inventory that they already have on hand.
Therefore, in the short run, aggregate supply can slope upward. As prices go up, businesses can choose to produce more, while as price levels fall, they can produce less.

term to know
Short-Run Aggregate Supply (SRAS)
The total amount of goods and services supplied in an economy in the short run, assumed to maintain a positive correlation between price and quantity because more can be produced through increased resource utilization, technological improvements, or other factors. SRAS is an upward-sloping curve.

3b. LRAS

The long-run aggregate supply curve (LRAS) is the total amount of goods and services supplied in an economy in the long run. This is a vertical or straight up-and-down line.

did you know
The LRAS curve is sometimes referred to as the Solow growth curve.

A graph depicting the concept of long-run aggregate supply or L R A S. The horizontal x-axis represents the GDP, and the vertical y-axis represents the Price Level. The curve for L R A S begins at a point in the middle of the x-axis and extends vertically upward, parallel to the y-axis.

The idea here is that we can ramp up our production in the short run, but this can really only get us so far. In the long run, we have a limited amount of resources, such as materials and workers. Therefore, that vertical line represents the current potential for how much we can produce.

Now, in order for that potential or production capacity to change, something else would need to change to increase our ability to produce more.

EXAMPLE

The invention of new technology might increase production capability and shift the supply curve over and to the right.

term to know
Long-Run Aggregate Supply (LRAS)
Assumed to be constant in the long run as, in the long run, resources are assumed to be used optimally, leaving no potential for increasing capacity. LRAS is a vertical curve.


4. Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Equilibrium

Now, the intersection of the SRAS curve and the aggregate demand curve will give us equilibrium.

Y*—note that it is now on the x-axis—represents the equilibrium level of production or output, also known as real GDP.

P* on the y-axis represents our current price level.

A graph depicting the aggregate supply/aggregate demand model. The horizontal x-axis represents the GDP, and the vertical y-axis represents the Price Level. The curve for aggregate supply or A S or short-run aggregate supply or S R A S starts at the origin (x equals 0, y equals 0) and slopes upward. The aggregate demand or A D curve begins at the endpoint of the y-axis and ends at the endpoint of the x-axis. The point at which the A S and the A D intersect is the equilibrium, which corresponds to the points Y* at the middle of the x-axis and P* at the middle of the y-axis. A horizontal dashed line from the point P* and a vertical dashed line from the point Y* extend to the equilibrium point.

In upcoming lessons, we will be using this graph to show what happens to the new equilibrium price level and real GDP when factors such as aggregate demand or aggregate supply change.

summary
Today, we learned about aggregate supply and aggregate demand by viewing the model and examining why they are shaped the way they are. Remember, aggregate demand slopes downward because of three reasons: the wealth effect, interest rate effect, and exchange rate effect. We also learned about the difference between the short-run aggregate supply (SRAS) and long-run aggregate supply (LRAS) curves. Lastly, we learned that the intersection of the SRAS and aggregate demand curves provides the equilibrium price level and output level, or real GDP.

Source: THIS TUTORIAL WAS AUTHORED BY KATE ESKRA FOR SOPHIA LEARNING. PLEASE SEE OUR TERMS OF USE.

Terms to Know
Aggregate Demand (AD)

The total amount of goods and services demanded in an economy at a specific point in time and at a prevailing price level.

Exchange Rate Effect

Exchange rate movements impact demand; domestic currency depreciation increases the cost of imports, resulting in a potential decrease in imports, M, while a lower domestic exchange rate increases foreign demand for domestic goods, increasing exports, X.

Interest Rate Effect

As interest rates fall, consumption increases because of the decrease in the cost of borrowing; as a result, purchases and business investment (consumption, C, and investment, I, respectively) both increase.

Long-Run Aggregate Supply (LRAS)

Assumed to be constant in the long run as, in the long run, resources are assumed to be used optimally, leaving no potential for increasing capacity. LRAS is a vertical curve.

Short-Run Aggregate Supply (SRAS)

The total amount of goods and services supplied in an economy in the short run, assumed to maintain a positive correlation between price and quantity because more can be produced through increased resource utilization, technological improvements, or other factors. SRAS is an upward-sloping curve.

Wealth Effect

Perception that wealth has increased, resulting in an increase in consumption, C.

Formulas to Know
Aggregate Demand

table attributes columnalign left end attributes row cell A D equals C plus I plus G plus left parenthesis X minus M right parenthesis end cell row cell w h e r e end cell row cell C equals C o n s u m p t i o n space o r space C o n s u m e r s space end cell row cell I equals I n v e s t m e n t comma space R e f e r r i n g space t o space B u s i n e s s e s space o r space F i r m s space end cell row cell G equals space G o v e r n m e n t s space end cell row cell X minus M equals E x p o r t s space M i n u s space I m p o r t s equals N e t space F o r e i g n space P u r c h a s e s space o f space D o m e s t i c space G o o d s end cell end table